Financial Constraints, Investment and Capital Structure: Implications From a Multi-Period Model
Preprint
- 1 January 2002
- preprint
- Published by Elsevier in SSRN Electronic Journal
Abstract
Intertemporal considerations have been largely ignored in the theory of capital structure. We provide a dynamic model that integrates firms' investment, financing and cash holding decisions in the presence of moral hazard. The distinguishing feature of this model is that it takes into account financially constrained firms' incentives to intertemporally allocate their liquidity between current and future projects. The incentive to intertemporally allocate liquidity comes from the concavity of a payoff function similar to that considered by Froot, Scharfstein and Stein (1993), which causes firms to behave as though they are risk averse when financially constrained. We show that once intertemporal considerations are brought in, stylized relationships that are often associated with models based on information asymmetry could be modified significantly, making it difficult to accept or reject such models empirically. Three such relationships that we examine are: (i) the relation between cash flows (or changes in liquidity) and investment, (ii) the relation between profitability and leverage, and (iii) the relation between future investment opportunities and leverage. As regards the first, we show that there is a critical level of liquid balances such that firms below this level exhibit greater cash flow sensitivity of investment than those above; however, the cash flow sensitivity of investment can be non-monotonic over a particular range of liquid balances (equivalently, firms' hurdle rates for projects can increase in the level of liquid balances). These results reconcile recent empirical evidence in Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988, 2000), Kaplan and Zingales (1995, 2000) and Cleary (1999). Second, we show that in a dynamic framework, firm's debt level could be positively related to profitability - contrary to the conventional wisdom of one-period models (but consistent with recent empirical evidence in MacKay and Phillips (2001)). Finally, an improvement in future growth opportunities can either cause the firm to increase or decrease its current leverage, depending on the nature of this improvement.Keywords
This publication has 20 references indexed in Scilit:
- Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities are Useful: A Comment on Kaplan and ZingalesThe Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2000
- The Relationship between Firm Investment and Financial StatusThe Journal of Finance, 1999
- Testing Tradeoff and Pecking Order Predictions About Dividends and DebtSSRN Electronic Journal, 1999
- The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle FrameworkPublished by National Bureau of Economic Research ,1998
- Private and Public Supply of LiquidityJournal of Political Economy, 1998
- Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and The Real SectorThe Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1997
- Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment: Response to Kaplan and ZingalesPublished by National Bureau of Economic Research ,1996
- Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy TransmissionPublished by National Bureau of Economic Research ,1995
- Risk Management: Coordinating Corporate Investment and Financing PoliciesThe Journal of Finance, 1993
- Financial Capacity and Output Fluctuations in an Economy with Multi-Period Financial RelationshipsThe Review of Economic Studies, 1992